Codes of conduct in Germany
(By Verbraucher - Zentrale Hamburg e.V.)
Codes of Conduct, Transparency
and Self Regulation:
Towards a Double Way of Protection of European Con-sumers’
legislation and Self-Regulation
Introduction
During the change of the millennium the economy’s organisation
is going through pervasive changes. More and more companies act
on markets outside their home countries (”globalisation”).
Instead of trade with industrially created products the offer of
services have become the centre of economical interest (”Service
Society”). And finally, due to the rapid development of computer
and network technology ”information” has become not
only a matter of numerous public discussions (for instance about
freedom of information or protection of personal data) but has also
been discovered as an economical source of extraordinary importance
(”Information Society”).
However, those changes, of course, are accompanied by a remarkable
uncertainty of all who are concerned and this represents a considerable
obstacle to the further economic development. In Germany this becomes
most obvious in the development of the so-called electronic market,
which is of extraordinary importance to the market of financial
services (see paper on ”Means of payment and financial services
at distance”) but in spite of highly-developed technology
still remains in its ”start-up” phase. On the one hand,
the use of services offered via Internet are still consid-ered being
tendential dangerous by a great number of number of consum-ers.
Correspondingly the consumer behaviour of the population as a whole
in this field is comparatively reluctant. On the other hand, companies
are also considerably unsure how conflicts that may arise can be
solved.
Those uncertainties might be eliminated in a rather traditional
way by the legislator. By enacting statutes, which would provide
increased transpar-ency in favour of the customers on the one hand
and legal certainty in favour of the companies on the other hand
the development especially of the electronic market might be accelerated
substantially. However, it is widely accepted that a formal legislation
done by the state can hardly satisfy the needs of economic processes,
which are rapidly and constantly changing their structures. Because
of these reasons some suggest/ it has been suggested that –
in addition to the classical regulation done by the state –
self-regulation mechanisms be drawn on. And this idea can also be
found in the European Directive on Electronic Commerce (Directive
2000/31/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 8 June
2000). Referring to Article 10 of this directive providers in the
member-states shall not only be obliged to arrange their offers
transparent in accordance to certain criteria. Additionally it shall
be provided, that customers are comprehensively informed about any
code of conduct the provider complies with. And furthermore, according
to the Article 16 of that same directive, consumer associations
as well as companies shall be expressively encouraged to work out
codes of conduct.
1. Incorporation of European Normatives in the German Legislation
The named European Normatives concerning the electronic market,
which will serve as an example to discuss the subject ”Codes
of conduct, trans-parency and self-regulation” in the following,
have been implemented mainly in § 312e of the German Civil
Code (Bürgerliches Gesetzbuch [BGB]). Thereby it is stipulated,
how providers who make use of ”tele- or mediaservices for
the purpose of concluding a contract about the delivery of goods
or the supply of services (electronic commerce contract)”
have to arrange their offers: According to § 312 sec. 1 No.
1 the customer has to be provided with ”appropriate, effective
and accessible technical means allowing the customer to identify
and correct input errors, prior to sending his order”. According
to No. 3 of the same stipulation providers have to ”acknowledge
the receipt of his [the customer’s] order by electronic means
without delay”. No. 4 determines that customers must be enabled,
”to retrieve and save the conditions of the contract including
general trade terms incorporated in the contract in reproducible
form”. Finally, according to Nr. 2, a customer must be supplied
with further information specified in the so-called ”Verordnung
über Informationspflichten nach Bürgerlichem Recht”
(BGB-InfoV) ”clearly and comprehensibly in good times before
the sending of his order”. With respect to § 3 BGB-InfoV
this information must contain: 1. information on ”the single
technical steps that lead to the concluding of a contract”
2. information on ”whether the contract text is stored by
the entrepreneur after the contract is concluded and whether it
is accessible for the customer” 3. information on ”how
the customer can identify and correct input errors by in accordance
to § 312e sec. 1 S. 1 no. 1 provided technical means prior
to the order” 4. information on ”lan-guages available
for the concluding of the contract” and 5. Information on
”any pertinent code of conduct the provider complies with,
aswell as a possibility of electronic access to these codes”.
2. Main Problems
In Germany the possibility of self-regulation by codes of conduct
named in BGB-InfoV is hardly of any importance. As there are such
codes they have primarily been worked out by provider associations
and are used as a kind of commercial or quality seal. Unfair competition
for the purpose of an intentional violation against the duty to
inform customers on such codes is therefore hardly imaginable. Neither
is it likely, that by such codes provid-ers comply with rules which
in an adequate way satisfy principal conflicts of interests in their
relations to the customer. The named other stipula-tions in §
312e BGB, which are meant to provide transparency in elec-tronic
commerce haven’t been of much help, either. In some cases
they even seem to have a counterproductive effect. This seems to
have its cause in the provision’s rather vague wording and
the fact that essential questions remain unsolved. Essential for
that purpose is first and foremost the question under which circumstances
a contract that has been initiated by the means of electronic communication
is considered legally valid. In this context, the tendency of many
providers to interpret plain ”hyperlink-clicking” or
”number-dialling” as a comprehensive agreement is of
crucial importance. In fact, this expanding attitude apparently
raised a certain fear of closing contracts unintentionally due to
the lack of experience and/or technical knowledge among the population
and can therefore be named as a main reason for many consumers’
reluctance to enter the electronic market at all. In Germany the
means of payment by so-called value added network services are the
most prominent example concerning this problem (see again paper
on ”Means of payment and financial serv-ices at distance”).
Taking this into consideration some of the valuations suggested
in § 312e BGB seem highly questionable. Is it – as implied
by § 3 No. 1 BGB-InfoV (Art. 10 of the directive on electronic
commerce) - exclusively up to providers to determine ”steps
that lead to the concluding of a contract”. And is lack of
providing information on those steps nothing but a matter of non-transparent
and therefore unfair competition without legal consequences concerning
the contractual relation to the customer (so apparently Heinrichs
in Palandt, BGB § 312e Rn 11)? Such valuations obviously object
to a legal principle, which is acknowledged in all evident legal
systems: a legally valid contract does not come into consideration
as long as transparency, which gives the possibility to the contracting
parties to gauge an offer and decide against or in favour of it.
In other words: legally, nobody has to be afraid to be obliged to
his detriment secretly – not even on the electronic market.
And it looks like the legislator’s failure to clarify this
is currently one of the main practical problems. However, practical
problems with the regulation of the electronic market in §
312e BGB also occurred in such cases in which the concluding of
a contract was in the customer’s best interest. The Munich
Oberlandesgericht (15.11.02 - 19 W 2631/02) for instance had to
decide whether an offer released on the Internet is binding even
if the given price is far below the usual level and held - apparently
rather instinctively than referring to an evident rule - that the
offer was just too good to rely on its validity. In another case
a customer received a confirming e-mail immediately after making
an order via the Internet, claimed performance on that basis, but
lost the case as the court was of the opinion that he could not
rely on a confirmation which was sent due to the obligation in §
312e No. 3 only (LG Gießen – 04.06.03 - 1 S 413/02).
3. Proposal on changes in the legislation
Those to a considerable part simply confusing provisions in §
312e BGB (see also Heinrichs in Palandt, BGB § 312e Rn 7) seem
to indicate that the legislator himself does not and most likely
cannot overlook the branch he wants to provide with an increased
transparency. Taking this into consid-eration the question arises,
whether the means of alternative regulation mechanisms, which might
satisfy changes in society and economy that occurred especially
on the electronic market more effective, are exhausted by being
marginally mentioned in § 3 No. 5 BGB-InfoV only. To compen-sate
the weak points of pure self-regulation, in Germany the term Regu-lierte
Selbstregulierung ([”regulated self-regulation”] Hoffmann-Riem,
Multimediapolitik vor neuen Herausforderungen, in: Rundfunk und
Fernse-hen 1995, S. 125) has been introduced into the discussion.
In the follow-ing it will be shown, which different models of ”regulated
self-regulation” have been worked out so far and to what extent
it makes sense to imple-ment such mechanisms in favour of consumer
protection on the electronic market.
a) Models of regulated self-regulation
Regulated self-regulation is plainly spoken a kind of self-regulation
which is adjusted to the legal system of a state or takes place
on the basis of law enacted by the state. As a result regulated
self-regulation, in compari-son to pure self-regulation, has an
increased degree of liability, but ideally does not require imperative
intervention by the state. For the purpose of implementing such
mechanisms, principally three models can be distin-guished. Firstly,
it is possible to oblige providers to work out or comply with codes
of conduct. Such codes of conduct would have to fulfil certain criteria
given by the state and be registered or certified by a regulating
institution. This model, which is, for instance, already put into
practice in Australia, can be named ”norm-centred” as
the registration of the code is the core of the regulation (see:
Schulz/Held Regulierte Selbstregulierung als Form des modernen Regierens,
2002). Secondly, the regulating or-ganisation that makes sure regulation
goals of the state are being fol-lowed might become the cardinal
point of the regulation. Similar to the model mentioned before,
this model offers the possibility to register or certificate the
regulating organisations in order to raise or provide a certain
regulation standard (”organisation-centred model”).
Within the framework of the ”supervision model”, finally,
imperative intervention by the state shall be prevented to begin
with by offering consulting to com-panies with the aim to inform
and show how conflicts with public interests can be avoided. This
is a common practice in the work of data protection agencies already
(”Auditing”).
b) Implementation of regulated self-regulation
When implementing self-regulating mechanisms, it is of extraordinary
importance to determine the goal of the regulation. For that purpose,
it is not enough to refer to consumer protection in general. In
fact, it has to be investigated attentively, whether it is necessary
to establish rules or control of existing rules is sufficient. The
”supervision model”, for in-stance, can work efficiently
only if existing rules already have been proved to be good in the
past and the regulation goal is simply to make sure they are generally
followed. This, for example, can be assumed with regard to legal
stipulations, that oblige companies to inform consumers about their
right to withdraw a contract under certain circumstances. However,
in many cases there are no such generally accepted rules or the
economical development has risen the need to change existing rules
in favour of an increased degree of consumer protection. Taking
a look at the electronic market in Germany – as mentioned
above – especially rules about the concluding of a contract
are missing. In those cases regulated self-regulation would have
to substitute legislation by the state. This is possi-ble only within
the framework of the ”norm-centred” model. Nevertheless,
it is necessary to propose a legal basis for such alternative regulation.
This is definitely not easy and preconditions immense preparatory
work. But it offers the possibility to involve consumer associations
as certification agency directly in the regulation. In comparison
to the current practice, which is vastly affected by the lack of
communication in between compa-nies and those associations, this
would mean a great progress.
|