Insurance coverage in Italy
(By Associazione Consumatori Piemonte )
“Italian legislation, law and problems about insurance and
civil liability”
Summary
1. Italian law about insurance contracts covering liability –
the civil code
2. Compulsory insurance for the circulation of vehicles –
what if a car accident happens?
3. Law and reality – a hard match in a not-so-free market
4. Problem solving attempts and everlasting issues – the last
years
1. Italian law about insurance contracts covering liability –
the civil code. In Italy, just like in so many other modern countries,
insurance of risks has been developing more and more since Lloyds’
opened their first office in London centuries ago.
Nowadays, corporations, firms and professionals use to protect themselves
from enterprise risks by signing insurance contracts with an ease
it was quite unpredictable when England ruled the waves and the
globalization process was just beginning thanks to a small number
of iron men on board of their wooden ships.
But now, also private citizens, not directly envolved in any commerce
or industry, are often called to sign insurance contracts. It’s
a long time now we’re used to call them “consumers”.
And it’s the hard reality of “consumers” of insurance
services we are called to examine here and now, Italy the year of
the Lord 2004.
According to the italian law system, insurance is a contract, regulated
by the civil code. The napoleonic idea of a separate code of commerce
is no more existing since 1942, when all the rules of the 1865 code
of commerce were included in the new civil code approved that year,
in wartime. In this new-coined melting pot, the entire category
of “commercial contracts”, those contracts which were
thought to be typical of enterprises and professionals, disappeared.
It was time now for everyone to have access to all typical contracts
regulated by law, and among these the insurance contract. As usual,
anyway, society had been going forward long before, and the new
law was just recognizing the state of fact. Fires, thefts, car accidents
were risks even a private, if wealthy enough of course, would be
gladly willing to think about before their possible unlucky realization.
Insurance covering was the ideal solution. In the same years, the
idea of an insurance compulsory by law for specific risks threatening
in a particular strong way the ordinate development of a modern
society, was already beeing given birth. In 1933 the totalitarian
government created the I.N.A.I.L., the powerful public insurance
covering work accidents. Enterprises were forced to declare to the
Institute the number and names of all their workers and employees,
and to contribute to its funds in proportion of the wages and salaries
they were paying to them (not without the contribution of the workers
themselves).
So, when the new civil code was enforced in 1942, the principles
and rules regulating the insurance typical contract were consolidated
well enough. Well enough indeed, considering how little the new
law articles have changed in more than 60 years of use. But, and
we shall see, the terrific changes in italian society could not
pass over without an influence – and what influence! –
on the insurance market. Legislation and law have been severely
changing of course; but not so much have the main principles been
touched as new specific laws have been enacted to regulate new aspects
of the reality it was uneasy to foresee in the new civil code days.
Let’s then see without delay what lawyers and citizens can
still read in the civil code, at articles 1882 and following, about
insurance contracts. We’ll contain our inquiry in the limits
of insurances covering damages provoked by an accident realizing
a risk. Italian law disciplines a second kind of insurances, those
paying a prize or a sum in case of an event “related to human
life”, such as the death of a parent. So, articles of interest
for our purpose end at number 1918; a first part, until article
1903, is unique for the two kinds of insurance, while articles since
1904 till 1918 specifically regulate insurance covering damages.
Art. 1882 provides a general definition of insurance contracts,
which have a typically gambling nature. The insurance company will
make a gamble about a possible accident involving the contractor:
if the accident will have place, the insurance will loose the gamble
and will have to pay a sum of money. If not, the insurance will
win and will retain the (generally much lesser) sum of money that
the contractor will have given to it.
Anyway, given that the idea of insurance is not the same of a simple
gamble, and that anyway the State is just not willing to encourage
gambling, many other norms are thought to strongly limit the gambling
side of the coin. But what’s the other side then, the encouraged
one? Of course, it is the transfer of risk to a stronger subject.
The possible accident is not an event like another: is a misfortune
realizing a specific risk involving directly the contractor (or
a third person in favour of whom the insurance is stipulated: artt.
1890 and 1891 civil code).
So, the insurance company has to be a strong one, for two reasons:
it’s the gambling side, and therefore it has to easily survive
even to strong losses; it’s a subject which will take risks
by default, and it will be having a particularly articulated structure
to evaluate the probability of realization of risks. Art. 1883 provides
that insurance companies have to be share corporations or public
bodies, and more specific provisions are written in other laws which
specify that it’s the government who authorizes insurance
companies given some specific pre-requisites such as a very strong
asset, similar to banks.
The insurance contract has to be written in order to bring evidence
of it in court (art. 1888 civil code). This should avoid undercover
agreements possibly transforming the insurance in a gamble.
The contractor has to tell the truth to the insurance companies
about facts influencing the risk; if not, the contract can be void
or anyway the company can withdraw from it (artt. 1892 and 1893
civile code; see also article 1906). If it wouldn’t so, the
contractor could easily make unfair gambles and obstacle the insurance
company in its efforts of calculate the risk realizing probabilities
(and therefore the correct price to ask in order to take the risk
on itself). For the same reason, the contractor has to inform the
insurance company of any fact which makes the risk easier to realize
(art. 1898 civil code).
The contract cannot last for more than ten years without providing
the right to withdraw for both parties after this term (art. 1899
civil code). This is because otherwise it would became too hard
for the insurance company to calculate the risk probability of realizing,
making the contract quite nearer to a simple gamble.
If the accident is provoked by the contractor itself, the insurance
won’t pay in case of accidents deriving either by will or
even by fault, but in this case the fault has to be serious (art.
1900 of the civil code).
A similar principle is involved by articles 1913, 1914 and 1915:
the contractor can’t avoid to act to limit damages. It would
be like partially provoke the accident and therefore it’s
not allowed for evident reasons. To act to limit damages implies
at first instance to immediately give advice to the insurance company
of the accident which happened (the term is fixed by law in just
three days).
A partial limitation to this principle is article 1918, allowing
the fundamental insurance against risks deriving by civil liability
of the contractor himself. We’ll examine more deeply this
kind of insurance, because it’s the one of main interest for
private citizens in modern society, in the field of civil liability
deriving from car accidents. Anyway, even if here is the action
of the contractor to determine the event foreseed by the insurance
contract, purposeful actions are excluded.
A main principle relating for insurance contracts covering risks
is provided by article 1905 of the civil code: the insurance company
is just liable in the limits of the damage suffered by the contractor:
no enrichment is allowed by law, or the insurance would become a
true gamble. This is true whatsoever the price payed by the contractor;
on the contrary, is well allowed (and practised) to determine in
the contract the maximum sum the insurance company will refund,
depending on the price payed and notwithstanding the effective damage
suffered. The same principle finds specifications in articles 1908,
1909, 1910 and 1911 of the civil code: if the object of the insurance
is a tangible good the liability of the insurance company is in
any case limited by the real original value of the good itself;
moreover, if the same good is the object of more than one insurance
contract, in any case the total sum perceived by the contractor
won’t exceed the value of the good itself.
In every case where a third part is liable for damages either on
a contractual or on a tort basis, the insurance company is allowed
to ask for them in its own favour directly to the third part (article
1916 of the civil code). In this way the insurance company will
take on itself the risks of an action at law against the responsible
but the general principles of liability won’t be touched.
These are the main rules provided by the civil code: general ones,
as usual, but implying strong and solid principles, still untouched
after more than sixty years. It’s when we enter in details
that we can observe the real life of modern society and insurance
contracts against risks directed to private consumers.
2. Compulsory insurance for the circulation of vehicles –
what if a car accident happens?
Most important among all types of insurance contracts a private
citizen signs normally, are contracts covering risks related to
the civil liability car drivers are subjected to. Car driving has
become a popular way of traveling in Italy in the fiftees and even
more in the sixtees. Nowadays, the rate of car per inhabitant is
one of the higher even in civilized countries, supported by a public
policy encouraging the private transport against the public one
(strong public investments in highways and roads and stagnation
in railway development is a leit-motiv of italian transports politics
in last decades).
So, the number of car accidents has fastly risen higher than ever.
Social problems, and costs, deriving from this new risk have produced
a huge amount of dedicated legislation: norms about driving safety,
of course (by the way, European Union has encouraged a strong process
of uniformation in this field), but also norms about insurance covering
civil liability deriving from car accidents, determining it as a
new type of compulsory insurance, and the first one involving private
citizens notwithstanding their professional activity. But why to
compel drivers to sign an insurance contract covering their liability
in case of accidents? About this issue there are two schools of
thnking. According to the first one, every increase in insurance
contracts for civil liability would determine an increase in negligence:
knowing that the insurance would pay for them would encourage people
to be careless about their own conduct. According to the second
one, to be unprotected from legal consequences of their own faults
have not enough significant meanings to people’s behaviour,
while social consequences for people involved in car accidents would
be far worse if they couldn’t afford on a sure compensation.
The latter of these ideas has prevailed, in Italy as everywhere
else. Market practises found even a way to partially guarantee that
the private maintains his own interest in a careful driving: the
“bonus-malus” contract scheme, according to whom every
year without accidents caused by fault lowers the price to pay for
the following year, while on the contrary every accident for which
the driver and his insurance are liable rises up the amount to pay.
Even if the “bonus-malus” formula is not compulsory,
and a driver is allowed to ask for a contract where the price is
fixed, such a contract is so more expensive that very fewpeople
even think about such a solution.
So, insurance for civil liability deriving from car accidents became
compulsory, and nowadays a vehicle is not allowed to run on public
roads if an insurance contract has not been signed for it. The insurance
has to cover both damages to things and to persons, until a fixed
minimum amount. There’s a specific Act regulating the matter,
outside of the driving code, which is the Law number 990 of April
29th 1969, later partially modified by Law number 54 of February
26th 1977 and Legislative Decree number 173 of May 26th 1997. Article
1 establishes the principle of compulsority on an individual vehicle
– insurance basis. In this way, each vehicle is covered by
insurance notwithstanding who’s the person driving, and even
if he’s driving against thw owner’s will. When the contract
is signed, the insurance company has to give to the contractor a
certificate and a mark, which he’s compelled to keep inside
the vehicle and to show attached to the front-window (article 7
law 990/1969). On the certificate and the mark is indicated the
date of expiry of the insurance, so that it’s always easy
to determine if a particular vehicle is allowed to run or not.
According with the specific goals insurance for risks related to
driving has to meet (certainty, speedness and easiness of refunding
proceeding, above all), law number 990/1969 provides many rules
which differ in relevant aspects from the civil code. One of the
most important is provided by article 18, according to whom the
third part who suffered the consequences can ask for refunding directly
to the insurance company, while according to general principles
of civil law this should be liable, in force of the contract signed,
just towards the contractor. Moreover, the insurance company has
to pay to the third part even in cases where its own contractual
liability towards its client is limited by the agreement (in limits
fixed by law) in boundaries more narrow than the tort liability
of its client towards the third part. In such cases, the insurance
company will have of course an action at law for redress against
its client.
But what in cases where a car accident is caused by a vehicle which
is not covered by insurance, or which succesfully escapes and couldn’t
be identified, or even which is covered by an insurance which goes
bankrupt? Articles 19-21 provide for the creation of a guarantee
fund, which covers the most important of these cases (deadly accidents,
or accidents where a person suffers a relevant permanent or a long
temporary physical damage). According to article 31, the fund is
constituted with a percentage amount from each single insurane contract
for civil liability from driving accidents signed. So, every authorized
insurance company contributes to the fund, and has to run it on
a turnary basis of three years. According to article 29, the insurance
company that happens to run the fund has an action at law for redress
against the responsible of the accident not covered by the insurance
or unidentified or against the insurance company involved in the
bankruptcy proceeding.
Articles 22-26 of law 990/1969 regulate the refunding proceeding
and its eventual judicial phase. In order to avoid unnecessary judicial
proceedings, an action can be suited only after a formal request
for refunding is sent to the insurance company and sixty days have
passed since its receiving (article 22). Article 23 provides for
the necessary involvement, in the judicial proceeding enacted by
the third part against the insurance company, of the direct civil
liable person whose liability is covered by the insurance. Finally,
article 24 allows the judge to assign a provisional sum to the damaged
person who alleges and proves to be in a state of urgent need.
These rules were surely a strong progress for all people involved
in a car accident, and nowadays it’s uncontested that the
compulsoriness of the insurance for civil liability deriving from
car accidents it’s absolutely necessary in modern italian
society. Even so, many problems have arisen as long as the circulation
of vehicles has been increasing more and more until today, with
strong consequences even on the number of accidents.
3. Law and reality – a hard match in a not-so-free market.
Let’s see now what’s been revealing to be wrong about
compulsory insurance for damages originated by the circulation of
vehicles. It’s always difficult to tell who’s to blame
for having been the first to break social unexpressed agreements,
and it’s just such the case of the relation between insurance
companies and private consumers. Anyway, the reality of such a relation
today is particularly bad, and we still have to examine the situation
starting from one of the two sides to end with the other. So, one
thing to notice is that many accidents, in Italy at least, have
been meant also many false accidents, that’s to say many frauds
against insurances. At a lesser level, real accidents have too often
been the startpoint for asking a refund higher than the correct
one. This state of things, from insurance companies’ point
of view, makes this branch of insurance unprofitable in comparison
with other ones. Italian national association of insurance companies
(A.N.I.A.) has always been blaming smaller and bigger frauds to
justify hostility from companies’ side in recovering damages.
Such an hostility has been long time beeing revealed by neverending
paying procedures more than by effective controls, with the result
of damaging more the unprepared and honest people in a need than
the true fraudsters. Moreover, there was the prices issue.
Prices have for a long time been regulated indirectly by law, due
to the public relevance the whole market sector had assumed with
law 990/1969. During the seventees and the eightees insurance companies
contracted with governments asking for increases; by law, they couldn’t
refuse to sign a contract if asked by a car owner, and they were
complaining about heavy losses they were suffering, with possible
sideeffects on all the insurance market and therefore on the national
economy. Insurance companies, as banks, were huge investors in national
industry and it has always been easy for them to threaten heavy
retreats. So, governments that followed were usually agreeing with
companies’ requests, and prices rised up, helped also by the
general price rising of those two decades. Time passing, anyway,
free market instances gained this sector too. European Union policies
preparing and following 1992 Maastricht Treaty strongly supported
free market in every sector of member countries’ economy.
About insurances, italian market was still strongly closed in itself,
and it was quite uneasy for a foreign corporation to have access
and make offers to italian consumers. Anyway, the blocked prices
system, with the government determining them according to law general
principles and unformal confrontation with insurance (national)
companies, was something of most different from European Union goals.
It was soon clear that the system would have to be completely changed,
and that prices liberalization would be a necessary step to unify
european insurance market. They were times of enthusiasm. Everything
looked fine; it was said that liberalization would have produced
a lowering in prices, arguing that free market and true competition
among italian and new, foreign, corporations would have good side-effects
for individual consumers too. It was not so long true that, where
a service has to be compulsory for people, its price had to be controlled
by government.
But things went in a different way. In the ninetees, all big corporations
rised up their prices as it was never been happening before, in
the regulated market system. The reasons declared by corporations
and A.N.I.A. were always the same: the unprofitability of the market
due to the high rate of accidents and of big and small frauds. In
the specific, but most important, case of accidents with small physical
damages to people, it was also blamed the italian physicians attitude
of recognizing quite always a small permanent damage (inability
of 1 – 3%), which of course increased a lot refunding costs.
Moreover, for a long time there was a strong uncertainty about how
to calculate the amount of money necessary to refund physical damages,
and it soon flourished a complex judge-made law which contributed
to increase the litigation rate. On the other side, it was noticed
that misorganizations were over-present in insurance companies and
specifically in offices related to civil liability for car accidents,
and that this was a most important basis for high prices. Quite
like it is usual in italian public offices, lack of technology and
excess in employees number (and wages) were present in italian insurance
companies as well. A role was played also by the high profits guaranteed
for external people and professionals working in some way with car
accidents (physicians, lawyers, car repairers and value experts).
But even this was not enough to fully explain the incredible price-rising.
Suspicions of a black agreement among all the main insurance companies
against the realization of a truly free market and for keeping profits
higher than normal were being growing at the same rate of the prices
themselves.
Soon prices became higher than everywhere else in Europe; insurance
companies told that even this was due to the particularly high number
of accidents and frauds in Italy. Refunding procedures remained
exaustingly long, though. Without a lawyer asking for a formal answer
and threatening a lawsuit at the same time, even simple cases continued
to be waiting for redress months or even years. Lawsuits continued
to be often necessary even when it shouldn’t be so, and at
their turn were long and expensive. When a physical damage to persons
was present, it was frequent to intent a criminal lawsuit against
the driver to make haste to the insurance company, but directly
threatening the contractor with a possible criminal conviction,
thus partially vanifying the specific purpose of all the insurance
system. Moreover, it proved to be especially difficult to get a
prompt and effective redress from the guarantee fund, run carelessly
by the turnary insurance company, even in cases where it was mostly
needed.
As the century was ending, it was clear to everyone at least that
the situation was critical. It was now the time for public authorities
to intervene once again, even if in the new context of a “free
market” system in an open european context.
4. Problem solving attempts and everlasting issues – the
last years
The situation of prices in insurance contracts, with the turning
of the new century, was getting worse and worse for private consumers.
In comparison with the regulated market system, there were now many
more kinds of offers: prices could now be different not only on
an individual “bonus-malus” basis, but also in relation
to the age and gender of the contractor (with females being favoured
as more careful drivers than men) and to the region of provenience.
Moreover, some foreign big company had been entering the market
and a totally new category of “low-cost” companies had
risen: the so-called “telephone-companies”, which cut
down costs erasing the necessity to refer to a traditional office,
with walls, structures and employees. Now it was possible to have
relation with one’s own insurance company just by phone, or
e-mail.
Even so, quite unpredictably, the effective rate of annual price
increase in the two years 2000 and 2001 was comprised between 50%
and 120% more than the year before! And this followed a period of
increase, not one of stagnation. In 1999, the D’Alema government
reacted to the heavy rise of insurance prices by stopping by decree
every increment for the following year. This kind of decision, criticized
as a late example of regulated market system, did not help anyway:
the year after the increase was even higher than before...
It was not until long time after than national anti-trust Authority
for free market opened a inquiry about the whole sector. The results
confirmed the worse suspicions. It was discovered the existence
of a data-base, shared among all the main insurance groups, used
to determine prices in a uniform and pre-determined way. Heavy sanctions
hit all the companies, and the judicial proceeding following the
appeal submitted by them confirmed the determinations of the Authority.
In the same years, a new law was enacted by Parliament, trying to
regulate some other aspects of the matter. It was the law number
57 of March 5th 2001. Prices issue was regulated with a transparency-oriented
style, respectful of the free market phylosophy. Insurance companies
were now compelled to declare the prices applied for nine typologies
of consumers and firms specified by article 1 (age, gender and type
of car were the elements to be taken into consideration). These
prices now had to be published and made visible to consumers in
insurance agencies. Moreover, they now had to be comunicated in
advance to the national authority of survey on insurances (I.S.V.A.P.)
and to the national consumer council (C.N.C.U.). I.S.V.A.P. gained
some more control power (article 2).
The new law was typically problem-solving oriented: specific norms
handling with specific issues, no pretense of re-regulating the
whole system. Besides the prices issue, the other question to solve
was the exhausting lenghtness of the refunding proceeding. Article
3 guaranteed to the consumer the right to have access to the final
acts of the proceeding, on the shape of what it was provided for
proceedings of public bodies by law 241 of year 1990. Finally, article
5 fixed a term of sixty days to end the refunding proceeding in
the simplest cases (no damages to persons, and demands presented
filling a form attached to the law), or of ninety days since the
receiving of the medical documents in cases of accidents with physical
damages to persons. The issue of the determination of the amount
of money due as a compensation for physical damages was for the
first time solved by a public law, even if just for minor damages
(up to 9% of permanent inability).
What now? The approach of law number 57 was a good one, but still
partial. Moreover, problems of enforcement still make some of the
new provisions uneffective, especially in southern areas and in
big cities. And prices, even after the intervention of national
anti-trust Authority, stay well higher of those applied in other
european countries. Free market system is still undisputed, as it
is compulsority of insurance for civil liability deriving by car
accidents. Anyway, these two principle seem someway to be contradictory
in themselves and compel public authorities to find out new ways
to limit unefficiences. Free market, according to neo-classical
economic theory, should be a solution in itself, and this is the
european point of view. Free market, anyway, has often to be enforced
by the State... this is another contradiction, but true as nothing
else. Nowadays, free market enforcing policies in insurances pass
through indipendent authorities (in Italy, anti-trust authority
and I.S.V.A.P.), and the two elements necessary to effective enforcements
are clear enough: resources and powers to find out violations and
the power to commit effective sanctions. In both of these fields
there’s still a long way to do.
Last but not least, an important role should be played by consumer
associations. Their step is the first one: to notice and denounce
possible violations, black agreements against free market and insurance
companies unefficiences which contribute to make this crucial sector
of economy one of the fullest of questions to solve. That’s
shouldbe the starting point for the successive activity of independent
authorities, too often shy in starting procedures of ascertainment
by themselves whenever the public opinion has not already submitted
the issue at the first page of the national agenda.
|